For months now, commentators have speculated about a so-called “Mar-a-Lago Accord” (MALA) — a hypothetical currency agreement designed to reshape the global trade and monetary order, evoking comparisons with Bretton Woods or the Plaza Accord. At its core lies the claim that the US dollar is “overvalued,” allegedly harming American industry. Yet this claim rests on shaky ground. Still, the plan calls for a deliberate weakening of the dollar.
MALA fits into a broader vision that merges trade policy with American security guarantees. In this framework, countries unwilling to cooperate would face tariffs and risk losing protection under the US security umbrella. If implemented, such a strategy would undermine trust in the United States and in the dollar as a global reserve currency — if not destroy it outright. That alone makes a formal MALA unlikely.
The MALA Theory
The theory begins with the premise that the United States suffers from unfair treatment in the global trading system. Because the dollar functions as the world’s reserve currency, it is supposedly overvalued. As a result, US manufacturers lose competitiveness.1
Stephen Miran, the current Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisers, published a “User's Guide to Restructuring the Global Trading System” in November 2024 with possible tools for correcting the trade deficit (Miran 2024). For him, the interconnection of trade and security policy is central. He sees import tariffs and devaluation of the dollar as the main instruments. The “security umbrella” of the US military apparatus should serve as a means of exerting pressure to enforce the policy.
Countries that want to continue to benefit from US military protection should agree to sell part of their dollar reserves. Remaining reserves are to be redeployed in long-term US government bonds in order to contribute to the financing of defense costs. The sale of the dollar reserves should weaken the US dollar, while the purchase of long-term bonds should keep interest rates at the long end of the curve low. In the event of a crisis, the Federal Reserve would provide the participating central banks with dollar liquidity via swap lines. Countries that refuse this arrangement would face punitive tariffs and exclusion from the American safety net.
MALA’s Flawed Premise
The diagnosis of an overvalued dollar does not hold up to scrutiny. The Economist’s Big Mac Index, for instance, currently shows a slight undervaluation of the dollar versus the euro.[2] And the real effective exchange rate of the dollar fluctuates around a stable long-term average, casting doubt on any structural overvaluation (Figure 1). The dollar’s current strength reflects a persistent shortfall in domestic savings, driven largely by fiscal policy.
Even if the US managed to weaken the dollar artificially, there’s no guarantee this would reduce trade deficits or revive American manufacturing. And the comparison with the 1985 Plaza Accord doesn’t hold. That agreement involved coordinated foreign exchange interventions among allies. Today, the Trump administration’s coercive approach hardly invites such cooperation especially when the largest holders of dollar reserves are in China, not in countries dependent on American defense guarantees (Miran 2024, p. 30).
Tariffs and Currency Policy: A Risky Game
For Miran (2024), import tariffs are an instrument for reindustrializing the USA, even if they contradict the MALA theory at key points. This is because tariffs are counteracted by currency appreciation if the imbalance of savings and investment underlying the foreign trade imbalance is not corrected. If a trade war breaks out, lower growth in the global economy will prevent the desired American reindustrialization.
Conclusion
A formal Mar-a-Lago Accord to devalue the dollar as outlined by Miran (2024) seems unlikely. Miran himself has acknowledged as much, recently stating that Trump currently focuses on tariffs rather than the full range of tools outlined in his own “handbook”.3
Instead of trying to manipulate the exchange rate, the US should confront the root of its external imbalances. Fiscal consolidation would reduce the need for foreign capital inflows, which in turn would lower the capital account surplus and shrink the current account deficit. Miran (2024) appears to miss this basic insight — and so, evidently, does Donald Trump.
References
Miran, Stephen (2024), A_Users_Guide_to_Restructuring_the_Global_Trading_System, Hudson Bay Capital.
__________________________________________________________________
1 See Miran (2024). The theory is not new and goes back to the "Triffin dilemma" formulated in the 1960s. According to this, a country that issues an international reserve currency must allow trade deficits so that monetary capital can flow abroad. At the same time, persistent trade deficits undermine confidence in the stability of this currency.
2 Siehe Our Big Mac index shows how burger prices differ across borders | The Economist
3 See Trump Economic Adviser Stephen Miran Rejects Short-Term Pain From Tariff Hikes - Bloomberg.
LEGAL NOTICE
One of the purposes of this publication is to serve as advertising material.
The information contained and opinions expressed in this publication reflect the views of Flossbach von Storch at the time of publication and are subject to change without prior notice. Forward-looking statements reflect the judgement and future expectations of Flossbach von Storch. Actual performance and results may, however, differ materially from such expectations. All information has been compiled with care. However, no guarantee is given as to the accuracy and completeness of information and no liability is accepted. The value of any investment can fall as well as rise and you may not get back the amount you invested
This publication does not constitute an offer to sell, purchase or subscribe to securities or other assets. The information and estimates contained herein do not constitute investment, legal and/or tax advice or any other form of recommendation. In particular, this information is not a replacement for suitable investor and product-related advice and, if required, advice from legal and/or tax advisers.
This publication is subject to copyright, trademark and intellectual property rights. The reproduction, distribution, making available for retrieval, or making available online (transfer to other websites) of the publication in whole or in part, in modified or unmodified form is only permitted with the prior written consent of Flossbach von Storch.
Past performance is not a reliable indicator of future performance.
© 2025 Flossbach von Storch. Alle Rechte vorbehalten.